where did I say any company making a profit is a bad thing? and tell you what, oil companies are "allowing" us this wonderful priveledge of getting their oil for an average of $3.15 a gallon here in lovely Massachusetts. You're out of your head if you think they aren't jumping for joy over all that money to roll around in at the expense of the population having to go into debt everytime they want to fill up their SUVs.
So do me a favor and back the fuck down- I don't give a shit about the role of government or much of anything to do with this thread, but to read LittleWing posting nonsense about how LITTLE profit the oil companies make is just retarded, and a lie.
it's not a lie. in 2004, exxon posted a record after-tax profit of more than $25 billion. gross profit, however, is different from gross profit margin. using this measure of profitability, exxon ranked 127th. in the twenty years from 1987 to 2006, exxon invested more ($279 billion) than it earned ($266 billion). their gross profits are a function of the size of the industry, not market power.
the price of gas has shot up for no shortage of reasons, many detailed in this thread. increased foreign and domestic demand, environmental regulations, and taxes have all applied upward pressure on prices. two rather underreported and misunderstood factors, however, have contributed to the dear market for oil: state-controlled supply and extraordinarily loose monetary policy.
first, 77% of the world's known oil reserves are in the hands of state-owned oil companies. these companies have neither the incentive nor the ability (thanks to rampant under-investment) to respond to the market's signals. iran has substituted nuclear ambitions for oil exploration and refining, mexico's production is slated to decrease 14% annually, russia's production is declining significantly (despite russian private sector oil production increasing by 47% between 1999 and 2004), and venezuela has suffered similarly since chavez took over. that certainly has something to do with government.
but the biggest culprit (and most germane to this thread) is the federal reserve, or more precisely, fiat money. the price of oil in terms of gold has, with few significant deviations, been stable. gas is $3.15/gallon in no small part because of the rapidity with which our currency has been devalued. this graph depicts gold in black and oil and gas in yellow. the dollar is the 0% line at the bottom. the graph's horizontal axis begins with bush's first day in office.
that the price of oil relative to the dollar has increased nearly 350% while the price of oil relative to gold has remained stable is a testament to the inflationary policies of the fed and the inherent vulnerability of fiat money. why, just look at the price of crude since the gold standard was abandoned in 1971...
central banks don't protect the purchasing power of national currencies. instead, they make sure that governments have a flow of dollars with which to spend at their whim. no discipline exists today on the creation of new money, the most important characteristic of the gold standard. the link to gold limited the capabilities of central banks to create money and, in turn, limited how much politicians could borrow and spend.
_________________
Fortuna69 wrote:
I will continue to not understand
Last edited by thodoks on Tue Mar 04, 2008 2:19 am, edited 1 time in total.
Joined: Sat Oct 16, 2004 10:53 pm Posts: 20537 Location: The City Of Trees
thodoks, I have a question for you about currency. Is it possible to have currency redeemable via several commodities instead of just one? Given the size of the money supply it seems impractical to return to only a gold standard if there isn't enough gold to redeem with if, say, everyone wanted to cash in. I guess I'm just trying to envision how a representative currency to commodities would work in this day and age.
Joined: Sat Oct 16, 2004 11:54 pm Posts: 12287 Location: Manguetown Gender: Male
3.15 dollars a gallon? Here a gallon is like 5 dollars
_________________ There's just no mercy in your eyes There ain't no time to set things right And I'm afraid I've lost the fight I'm just a painful reminder Another day you leave behind
Joined: Sun Oct 17, 2004 4:01 am Posts: 19477 Location: Brooklyn NY
$úñ_DëV|L wrote:
glorified_version wrote:
$úñ_DëV|L wrote:
Texas does emit the most greenhouses in the country, but it is also the country's largest producer of petroleum and plastics. That has more to do with the very fact that those things are being produced than Texas' actual government policies. If you produce it somewhere else, the greenhouse gases would just be coming from that place instead.
This is definitely not true. Some places' environmental policies on the whole are lackadaisical at best, Texas being one of them. It's important to realize that the laws regarding such things are made by the people living there and factors such as the amount of pollution a state emits really have no state, national, or universal application.
I don't think you get my point. Perhaps Texas' environmental policies allow for more petroleum and plastic production, but the process itself will emit the same pollution no matter where it takes place. And as long as there is demand for plastic and petroleum, that production will take place *somewhere*.
NOT speaking from a political sense, you're oversimplifying what the industry does even on a systematic level. It's not the same "somewhere else," or anywhere. As you know, the production of oil is a huge and intricate process which can be substantially destructive to the environment. It's extracted, (or drudged), processed, and then wastes are disposed, etc. How much pollution Texas gets depends if people in Texas give a shit, whether they're the oil company or they're citizens.
Many factors that go into oil production are usually overseen by government regulators. Petroleum production on the whole is a necessary evil, because civilization needs it. It isn't a matter of the Texas legislature stepping in to tell oil companies to stop producing oil altogether simply because it's bad. And even with new regulations, Texas would still have pollution issues. Unfortunately, there are some rather obvious (and common) cases of severe neglect on behalf of oil (and mining, and drilling, and logging) companies because they want to cut costs and usually the bureaucracy isn't there to prevent them from not doing so. Either that, or bought off.
It's time to stop portraying these companies as victims. For example, spending $1000 to clean up an acre of land as opposed to spending $1500 to do it RIGHT is correct only for short-term gain. And it's nearly impossible to tell this to someone like Dick Cheney because that doesn't fit into his world view.
Quote:
I'll let the fact that people are moving out of Ohio and into Texas speak for itself.
And I would definitely say the opportunity to become filthy rich is far more important than not having huge social disparity. Why? Because not having huge social disparity implies that everybody is poor. People who don't have the opportunity to get ahead have no motivation to produce, and I think that is what this Ohio vs. Texas comparison supports. It is much better for some people to be rich and some people to struggle than for everybody to struggle. That's why half the people I work with moved here from Michigan--they're educated, there aren't any jobs there for them, and they have to pay more taxes on top of that. The "tax the corporations and the non-poor" model is not sustainable, and it will keep any state mired that continues to implement it.
Ohio is losing jobs, not physical people. Everything else is a mere ideological difference, nothing more.
_________________
LittleWing sometime in July 2007 wrote:
Unfortunately, it's so elementary, and the big time investors behind the drive in the stock market aren't so stupid. This isn't the false economy of 2000.
thodoks, I have a question for you about currency. Is it possible to have currency redeemable via several commodities instead of just one?
absolutely. for the sake of clarity (and brevity), the "gold standard" is simply a convenient nomenclature for "competing currencies." gold and silver (and to a lesser extent, other less precious metals) were the commodities most favored by the market prior to the establishment of central banks and fiat money. it is telling that the price of gold is often a bellwether of coming inflation; a run-up in the price of gold often portends trouble in liquidity markets.
Green Habit wrote:
Given the size of the money supply it seems impractical to return to only a gold standard if there isn't enough gold to redeem with if, say, everyone wanted to cash in. I guess I'm just trying to envision how a representative currency to commodities would work in this day and age.
while i don't want to hijack this thread and go too far into the weeds, i will add that your second point speaks not so much to any inherent complications of a gold standard (or any commodity-backed money) as it does to the tendency of a fractional-reserve banking system, such as our own, to be functionally insolvent. with a reserve requirement of 10%, all that has to happen for your local bank to go broke (notwithstanding an emergency loan from the fed) is for depositors to demand 10.1%, or more, of their deposits. this is, of course, a gross oversimplification. but the point remains: for every $1,000 in circulation, your bank only has $100 on hand. or does it?
the jelly to the gold standard's peanut butter is 100% reserve banking, which is exactly as it sounds: every dollar in circulation is backed by some commodity. the upshot is a far more stable currency and banking industry, and as the economy's productivity increases, steadily falling price levels and commensurate increases in the purchasing power of each monetary unit produce higher living standards. we are so conditioned by permanent price inflation (bernanke often speaks of his 2% inflation target) that the idea of consistently falling prices is difficult to grasp.
as for the nitty-gritty of the transition from fiat money to commodity money, i don't pretend to know. i've done far less research on the nuts and bolts of said transition than i have on fractional-reserve banking versus 100% reserve banking, perhaps because i realize that such an event is, at best, a remote possibility.
Joined: Sat Oct 16, 2004 10:51 pm Posts: 14534 Location: Mesa,AZ
glorified_version wrote:
$úñ_DëV|L wrote:
glorified_version wrote:
$úñ_DëV|L wrote:
Texas does emit the most greenhouses in the country, but it is also the country's largest producer of petroleum and plastics. That has more to do with the very fact that those things are being produced than Texas' actual government policies. If you produce it somewhere else, the greenhouse gases would just be coming from that place instead.
This is definitely not true. Some places' environmental policies on the whole are lackadaisical at best, Texas being one of them. It's important to realize that the laws regarding such things are made by the people living there and factors such as the amount of pollution a state emits really have no state, national, or universal application.
I don't think you get my point. Perhaps Texas' environmental policies allow for more petroleum and plastic production, but the process itself will emit the same pollution no matter where it takes place. And as long as there is demand for plastic and petroleum, that production will take place *somewhere*.
NOT speaking from a political sense, you're oversimplifying what the industry does even on a systematic level. It's not the same "somewhere else," or anywhere. As you know, the production of oil is a huge and intricate process which can be substantially destructive to the environment. It's extracted, (or drudged), processed, and then wastes are disposed, etc. How much pollution Texas gets depends if people in Texas give a shit, whether they're the oil company or they're citizens.
Many factors that go into oil production are usually overseen by government regulators. Petroleum production on the whole is a necessary evil, because civilization needs it. It isn't a matter of the Texas legislature stepping in to tell oil companies to stop producing oil altogether simply because it's bad. And even with new regulations, Texas would still have pollution issues. Unfortunately, there are some rather obvious (and common) cases of severe neglect on behalf of oil (and mining, and drilling, and logging) companies because they want to cut costs and usually the bureaucracy isn't there to prevent them from not doing so. Either that, or bought off.
It's time to stop portraying these companies as victims. For example, spending $1000 to clean up an acre of land as opposed to spending $1500 to do it RIGHT is correct only for short-term gain. And it's nearly impossible to tell this to someone like Dick Cheney because that doesn't fit into his world view.
So, let's say Texas tightens up the regulations on oil companies. What happens? Costs increase for everybody. I don't see the point of adding some inefficient bureaucracy to suck money out of the economy just for some perceived environmental benefit that may or may not actually be achieved. But it's not like their environment is being destroyed over there... Houston has pollution, but not really any more than, say, L.A. Texas is certainly far less polluted than any developing nation, even with petroleum production.
But the simple fact is, if it's really important for oil companies to find more ecofriendly ways to produce gas, taxes is not the answer, and is only counter-productive. But I tend to believe they're working on it on their own, judging by the massive amounts of money they've funneled into research.
Quote:
Quote:
I'll let the fact that people are moving out of Ohio and into Texas speak for itself.
And I would definitely say the opportunity to become filthy rich is far more important than not having huge social disparity. Why? Because not having huge social disparity implies that everybody is poor. People who don't have the opportunity to get ahead have no motivation to produce, and I think that is what this Ohio vs. Texas comparison supports. It is much better for some people to be rich and some people to struggle than for everybody to struggle. That's why half the people I work with moved here from Michigan--they're educated, there aren't any jobs there for them, and they have to pay more taxes on top of that. The "tax the corporations and the non-poor" model is not sustainable, and it will keep any state mired that continues to implement it.
Ohio is losing jobs, not physical people. Everything else is a mere ideological difference, nothing more.
Ohio is losing physical people. Ohio had a net migration of -362,000 from 1997 to 2007, and only experienced population stability through live births.
_________________
John Adams wrote:
In my many years I have come to a conclusion that one useless man is a shame, two is a law firm, and three or more is a congress.
Joined: Sun Oct 17, 2004 4:01 am Posts: 19477 Location: Brooklyn NY
$úñ_DëV|L wrote:
I don't see the point of adding some inefficient bureaucracy to suck money out of the economy just for some perceived environmental benefit that may or may not actually be achieved. But it's not like their environment is being destroyed over there... Houston has pollution, but not really any more than, say, L.A.
Sucking money out of the economy?
Bro...when an oil company is documented polluting public land, air, or water to cut costs (a search on google should notify you that it happens all the time), that's sucking money out of the economy. It means that the land, air, or water is potentially of no use to human beings for decades if not hundreds or thousands of years. What makes you think that damage to topsoil on a plot of land or water chemistry in nearby streams is merely just "perceived," and the environmental benefits to protection are a "maybe?" At what point does a negative, net impact on surrounding populations of wildlife or fish become bigger than just a local business or state issue? What happens when it becomes another state's issue, or another business's issue? Or is that fair competition?
Studying ecology and the environment is based in the hard sciences: Field research, testing, experimenting, hypothesizing, more testing, looking into empirical evidence, data analysis, rationalizing, theorizing, examining years and years worth of information. People who are taken seriously enough to be published in scientific and academic journals as well as newspapers and other publications have undergone rigorous peer-review and criticism and are informed by pure, empirical knowledge to the best of their ability. They've made it their life's work to inform people about the world and so be it if that includes potential effects by any human institution, whether private or governmental. That doesn't make them ideological proponents of Marxist-Leninism. In other words, the reality surrounding the environmental movement probably doesn't fit your or LittleWing's cartoonish impression of tree-hugging activism trying to disrupt hardworking, good-natured people in industry. Activism isn't a bad card to play either considering the hand of the business establishment.
And this is definitely more of a hard science than the rhetoric from Econ 101 that you can't resist from borrowing. The fact is that severe pollution can be perceived as complete negligence in the court of public opinion or LAW, as was the case with Exxon last week. I'm sure the left-wing media is to blame for public concern about corporate chicanery; not your own ignorance. Awareness is better than any overwrought legislation or motive to make a profit. You're a sensible person, make up your own mind.
Private/corporate funding: a relatively controversial topic with good and bad consequences. Good in theory, oftentimes atrocious in practice.
_________________
LittleWing sometime in July 2007 wrote:
Unfortunately, it's so elementary, and the big time investors behind the drive in the stock market aren't so stupid. This isn't the false economy of 2000.
Last edited by glorified_version on Tue Mar 04, 2008 8:55 am, edited 1 time in total.
10.11.2007 Science's Worst Enemy: Corporate Funding And you thought the Bush administration was bad. by Jennifer Washburn
In recent years there have been a number of highly visible attacks on American science, everything from the fundamentalist assault on evolution to the Bush administration’s strong-arming of government scientists. But for many people who pay close attention to research and development (R&D), the biggest threat to science has been quietly occurring under the radar, even though it may be changing the very foundation of American innovation. The threat is money—specifically, the decline of government support for science and the growing dominance of private spending over American research.
The trend is undeniable. In 1965, the federal government financed more than 60 percent of all R&D in the United States. By 2006, the balance had flipped, with 65 percent of R&D in this country being funded by private interests. According to the American Association for the Advancement of Science, several of the nation’s science-driven agencies—the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA), the Department of Agriculture, the Department of the Interior, and NASA—have been losing funding, leading to more “outsourcing” of what were once governmental science functions. The EPA, for example, recently began conducting the first nationwide study on the air quality effects of large-scale animal production. Livestock producers, not taxpayers, are slated to pay for the study. “The government is clearly increasing its reliance on industry and forming ‘joint ventures’ to accomplish research that it is unable to afford on its own anymore,” says Merrill Goozner, a program director at the Center for Science in the Public Interest, a consumer advocacy group.
Research universities, too, are rapidly privatizing. Both public and private institutions now receive a shrinking portion of their overall funding from government sources. They are looking instead to private industry and other commercial activities to enhance their funding. Last summer, an investigation by the San Jose Mercury News found that one-third of Stanford University’s medical school administrators and department heads now have reported financial conflicts of interest related to their own research. These included stock options, consulting fees, and patents.
Is all this truly harmful to science? Some experts argue that corporate support is actually beneficial because it provides enhanced funding for R&D, speeds the transfer of new knowledge to industry, and boosts economic growth. “It isn’t enough to create new knowledge,” says Richard Zare, a professor of chemistry at Stanford University. “You need to transfer that knowledge for the betterment of society. That’s why I don’t want to set up this conflict of interest problem to such a heightened level of hysteria whereby you can’t get universities cooperating with industry.”
Even many industry leaders worry that the current mix of private and public funding is out of balance, however. In 2005, a panel of National Academies (the National Academy of Sciences, the National Academy of Engineering, and the Institute of Medicine) that included both industry and academic members (including Zare) concluded that corporate R&D “cannot and should not replace federal R&D.” (pdf) Norman Augustine, the panel’s chairman and a former CEO at Lockheed Martin, noted that market pressures have compelled industry to put nearly all its investment into applied research, not the riskier basic science that drives innovation 10 to 15 years out.
Others fear that if the balance tips too far, the “public interest” side of the science system—known for its commitment to independence and objectivity—will atrophy. Earlier this year, former FDA commissioner Jane Henney remarked that “it’s getting much more difficult to get that pure person with no conflicts at all. . . . The question becomes both one of disclosure and how much of a conflict you can have and still be seen as an objective and knowledgeable reviewer of information.” More than half the scientists at the U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service who responded to a survey conducted by the Union of Concerned Scientists in 2005 agreed that “commercial interests have inappropriately induced the reversal or withdrawal of scientific conclusions or decisions through political intervention.”
Merrill Goozner argues that the danger runs deeper. “In many precincts of the scientific enterprise, the needs of industry have become paramount,” he says, turning science into “a contested terrain” where facts are increasingly contingent on who is funding the research. “The whole scientific revolution, which was a product of the Enlightenment, is threatened when you commercialize science,” he warns.
So is private funding a boon or a bane for American science? The answer, like good science itself, requires looking carefully at how the phenomenon is playing out in the real world.
Steven Nissen is perhaps the most prominent physician speaking out about the pharmaceutical industry’s growing influence over medical research. An esteemed cardiologist at the Cleveland Clinic, Nissen has written more than 300 articles and served as the immediate past president of the American College of Cardiology. Working in a bustling academia-affiliated medical center has given Nissen a unique perspective on the benefits and risks of privatization.
In the past, academic medical investigators strove to maintain “arm’s-length relationships with their corporate sponsors,” says Marcia Angell, a former editor in chief at The New England Journal of Medicine. That changed with the rise of biotechnology and the passage of landmark congressional legislation known as the Bayh-Dole Act. Passed in 1980, the act granted universities and their professors automatic rights to own and commercialize federally funded research. The goal was to unlock financial incentives that would speed the pace of American scientific innovation. Overnight, many of the cultural taboos associated with overt commercial profiteering on campus began to evaporate.
Nissen believes that interactions between academia and industry are crucial to the development of new treatments. He also accepts sponsored research grants from industry, both to test drugs and develop new treatments, although he tries to limit his personal financial conflicts of interest by requiring that any other consulting fees and honoraria be given directly to charity. Still, he is clearly troubled by the threat that privatization poses to academic autonomy—and to research objectivity. “We can only make good decisions in science when all of the information is available for physicians, scientists, and patients to review,” he says. But drug companies are increasingly keeping physicians and their patients in the dark.
Last year, Nissen grew suspicious about possible health risks associated with GlaxoSmithKline’s top-selling diabetes drug, Avandia. “We requested access to the original patient-level data,” he says, but “we were not afforded access.” Nissen wasn’t surprised; for years he has perceived a growing tendency by the drug industry to suppress negative research data.
Searching the Internet, Nissen stumbled upon a remarkable cache of data belonging to Glaxo. His search unearthed 42 Avandia clinical trials—only 15 of which had ever been published. Nissen didn’t know it at the time, but the reason Glaxo’s data were just sitting there on the Web was the outcome of a lawsuit filed by former New York attorney general (and current governor) Eliot Spitzer in 2004. The lawsuit alleged that Glaxo had concealed negative trial data associated with its popular antidepressant drug, Paxil. When the data were properly analyzed, they showed that children given Paxil were actually two times more likely to experience suicidal thinking and behavior than children given a placebo, or sugar pill. When Glaxo settled the suit, it denied having suppressed data and consented to posting results of all its clinical trials online—including its data on Avandia.
Nissen knew there were limitations to the public information he had. He lacked any original patient-level information, and a meta-analysis of prior drug studies is always less powerful than a large prospective, randomized clinical trial. This May, however, Nissen felt compelled to alert doctors and patients to what he had found.
Publishing in The New England Journal of Medicine, Nissen reported that Avandia raised the risk of heart attacks in patients by 43 percent. The news made front-page headlines. Two days later, the FDA, which had already been assessing the health risks of Avandia, imposed its toughest warning label, the “black box,” on the drug, as well as on Actos, another drug used to treat diabetes.
At a subsequent congressional hearing chaired by Representative Henry Waxman, it came to light that the FDA had known about Avandia’s risks for some time. Rosemary Johann-Liang, a former FDA drug safety supervisor, had recommended a black box warning label for Avandia due to its harmful effects on the heart one year prior to Nissen’s publication. Glaxo’s own meta-analysis, presented to the FDA in 2006, showed a 31 percent increased risk of heart attacks. Yet according to Johann-Liang, “my recommending a heart failure box warning was not well received by my superiors, and I was told that I would not be overseeing that project.” She was also told to obtain her supervisors’ approval before making any future black box recommendations. After the hearing, the FDA completed its own meta-analysis of the original patient data and found virtually the same heart risks Nissen had reported.
Nevertheless, Nissen found himself under attack, often by people with explicit financial ties to the drug industry. His challengers have included Valentin Fuster, who wrote a critique of Nissen’s work in Nature Clinical Practice Cardiovascular Medicine. Fuster receives Glaxo funding and serves as the chairman of Glaxo’s Research and Education Foundation. Peter Pitts wrote a stinging attack on Nissen in The Washington Times; he is a senior vice president at the PR firm Manning Selvage & Lee, which represents Big Pharma, including Glaxo. Douglas Arbesfeld, a senior communications consultant at the FDA, disparaged Nissen in a biting e-mail to the media. He formerly worked as a spokesman for Johnson & Johnson.
Press reports over the last 15 years detail how whistle-blowers inside academia and within the FDA who have attempted to expose drug-research and safety issues have been pressured. Some were threatened with legal action, others punished by their superiors and discredited. “Whenever we’ve raised safety questions about drugs,” Nissen says, “there’s always been a reaction like this. Exactly the same thing happened in 2001 when we published a manuscript that suggested that Vioxx might be causing excess heart attacks.” Nissen was coauthor of one of the first studies on the dangers of Vioxx. Three years later, Merck pulled the drug from the market. By that time, one FDA analyst estimates, the drug had contributed to up to 139,000 heart attacks. (A Merck representative states that the paper from which the estimate of 139,000 was derived had “serious limitations” and did not necessarily reflect the views of the FDA.)
Experiences like these have bolstered Nissen’s position that the independent research system needs to be protected and preserved. “I think having independent physicians leading the study and analyzing the data is the best way to protect against biases in the reporting of results.” But increasingly, he says, the pharmaceutical industry is farming out its clinical trials to for-profit entities, known as contract research organizations. Independent academic investigators are getting shut out.
The numbers bear Nissen out. Big Pharma now finances approximately 70 percent of the nation’s clinical drug research. In the past, most of this sponsored-research money went to academic medical centers; today an estimated 75 percent flows to for-profit contract research firms.
Even when academic physicians are involved, often they don’t enjoy anything close to true research independence, Nissen says: “Academic physicians are still involved in the leadership of the study, but not fundamentally in the design of the study, or in the key aspects of the execution of the study.” Often, he notes, the industry sponsor will prevent the academic investigator from performing any independent analysis of the complete raw data related to his or her research. “The physician gets a printout of the main results,” Nissen says, “but the actual analysis itself is done by statisticians within the companies.”
In 2001, the editors of 12 leading medical journals, including The New England Journal of Medicine and The Lancet, expressed their shock at what was happening to independent scientific inquiry. Many of these journals implemented new policies requiring authors to sign a statement verifying that they had unfettered access to the complete trial data, took full responsibility for the conduct of the trial, and controlled the decision to publish.
But cases of commercial influence continue to surface, often making headlines, prompting some editors, like Drummond Rennie, an editor at The Journal of the American Medical Association, to sound defeated: “You know, if people lie to us, all we can do is reveal that lies were told afterwards—and usually they’re lying on their way to the bank.”
Like medical researchers, university professors have long collaborated with private industry. In recent years, though, the nature and scope of these relationships have changed dramatically. The University of California system is a prime example.
Lisa Bero, a pharmacologist and health policy researcher at the University of California at San Francisco (UCSF), has immersed herself in studying the relationship between industry-funded science and research quality. She also chairs the internal UCSF committee that reviews professors’ financial conflicts of interest. “Corporate money is certainly moving into academia,” Bero says. “And now we have all these new models of funding. I mean, before, it used to be just the investigator who goes out and gets an industry grant. Now entire departments are being funded by one company.”
Early this year, BP (formerly British Petroleum) announced it was signing the largest proposed academia-industry research alliance in U.S. history: a 10-year, $500 million agreement with UC Berkeley, Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory, and the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign to study biofuels and the production of genetically modified crops that might improve their energy efficiency. As of this writing, the deal is still being negotiated. However, according to Berkeley’s official proposal, released in early March, the deal is unusual in many respects. First, it is huge, spanning roughly 25 labs at three campuses. Second, it permits 50 BP employees to lease commercial research space on campus, side by side with Berkeley’s traditional academic labs. On the academic side, all research is publishable. On the BP side, by contrast, the research is proprietary; there is no obligation to publish.
Tadeusz Patzek, an engineering professor at Berkeley who formerly worked as a scientist at Shell, believes the deal compromises the university’s ability to look objectively at long-term energy solutions to global warming. He fears that professors, following the money, will steer their research toward BP’s specified area of commercial interest—biofuels—without adequately exploring other energy options. Patzek’s concerns are supported by survey research in the medical field conducted by David Blumenthal and Eric Campbell, policy analysts at Harvard University. Their research finds that academic scientists who receive industry funding are significantly more likely to select research projects that have a higher potential for commercial application. Industry ties, they report, are also associated with longer delays on publication, confidentiality restrictions, and a greater withholding of information from academic peers.
Richard Nelson, a professor emeritus of economics at Columbia University, finds these commercial restraints on the free flow of academic knowledge troubling from the standpoint of innovation. The biggest change resulting from the Bayh-Dole Act, he says, is the way that academic knowledge is transferred to industry. In the past, university research was picked up by industry mostly through open means: publications, conferences, consulting, et cetera. After the passage of Bayh-Dole, patenting and licensing became more common—not because it was always the only or best way to transfer knowledge to industry but because it enabled universities and their professors to share in the profits.
The rise in academic patenting and licensing also gives universities and their professors growing financial ties to outside companies, not to mention growing investments in their own research (including patent rights, stockholdings, and royalty shares). “What academic institutions always argue is that they have sufficient safeguards in place to protect against any influences on the academic research,” Bero says. “Here at UCSF I sit on what’s called a conflict of interest advisory committee, and believe me, I’m familiar with our gazillion policies. Universities do have a lot of policies, but I would argue that they’re not sufficient.”
Bero points to a large body of research by herself and others that shows industry-funded studies preferentially reach conclusions that favor sponsors’ products or interests. One meta-analysis published in BMJ (British Medical Journal) found that pharmaceutical-industry-funded research was four times more likely to reflect favorably on a drug than research not financed by industry. Even when Bero controls for a variety of other factors, she finds that the effect of industry funding on the research outcome is huge. Research on secondhand smoke conducted by researchers with industry ties is 88 times more likely to find no harm; industry-funded studies comparing cholesterol drugs are 20 times more likely to favor the sponsor’s drug.
This happens, Bero contends, because private industry has become increasingly sophisticated about how it uses “science” to achieve its commercial objectives. “We’ve looked at the tobacco and pharmaceutical industries, and now we’re looking at legal documents pertaining to the asbestos, vinyl chloride, and lead industries,” she reports. The techniques they use are remarkably similar: Positive research gets published; negative research doesn’t. The sponsor’s drug is given at a higher dosage than the competitor’s drug. The sponsors control study design, access to data, and statistical analysis. They ghostwrite articles and pay prominent academics to sign on as “authors.”
Bero observes that many professors are desperate to find funding for their research, and a lot of them are naive about the potential for industry influence. “You never think you’re at risk for conflicts of interest,” she says. “You always think your coworker is.”
University policies governing conflicts of interest and research integrity vary widely from campus to campus—and most still have a lot of holes, Bero contends. One 2005 study examining more than 100 academic medical centers found that half would allow the corporate sponsor to write manuscripts reporting on study results and only allow faculty to “suggest revisions”—a policy basically authorizing commercial ghostwriting of academic research. Thirty-five percent allowed the sponsor to store clinical trial data and release only portions to the investigator; 62 percent allowed the sponsor to alter the study design after the researchers and the sponsor had signed an agreement.
“I think universities really need to think more carefully about protecting their investigators from their sponsors,” Bero says. “A lot of these things are not illegal; there’s no university policy against them.”
Most Americans rarely think of science as something crucial to the way government operates. Yet, as Seth Shulman explains in his book Undermining Science, “the U.S. government runs on information—vast amounts of it.” Scientists at the Department of Agriculture track airborne bacteria resulting from farm wastes, experts at the Centers for Disease Control examine samples to help guard against large-scale disease outbreaks, and regulators at the EPA set standards for pesticide use and exposure. By necessity, most of these federal agencies work closely with industry, but more and more their internal functions are also being privatized. Scientific advisory panels are frequently filled with experts who have close financial and other ties to the same industries that manufacture the products they are reviewing. Agencies also outsource their regulatory functions to private-sector contractors and forge new public-private research ventures.
Consider the Center for the Evaluation of Risks to Human Reproduction, part of the National Institutes of Health (NIH). The center has only two full-time employees and one part-time; until recently the rest of the center’s workforce was supplied by Sciences International (SI), a private consulting firm that has been funded by more than 40 chemical industry clients. For nearly a decade, the center had been outsourcing much of its work to SI, which assessed health risks and drafted reviews for 21 chemicals that the center was reviewing for their possible impact on human reproductive health. This April, NIH terminated its contract with SI after learning that the company or its employees had business ties to the chemical industry.
Another variant of privatization can be seen at the FDA, which currently draws more than 50 percent of its total drug review budget from user fees paid by the pharmaceutical industry. David Kessler, a former head of the FDA, recently told The Wall Street Journal, “There is no doubt that user fees give the industry leverage on setting the agency’s priorities. There are significant risks.” Marcia Angell, the former editor of The New England Journal of Medicine, puts it more bluntly: “The FDA has been captured by the industry it is supposed to regulate.”
What’s troubling about these trends is that most federal agencies are poorly equipped to protect themselves from undue corporate influence, says David Michaels, an epidemiologist at George Washington University and former assistant secretary for environment, safety, and health at the Department of Energy. Regulatory agencies must rely on large quantities of scientific evidence submitted to them by private industry. This evidence is needed to determine the hazards and characteristics of industrial chemicals, products, and wastes. But according to Michaels, most of these federal agencies lack even the most rudimentary tools that a medical journal editor would use to assess the quality and scientific integrity of industry-funded research.
At the EPA and the Occupational Safety and Health Administration, regulators do not have the authority to inquire as to who paid for the studies they receive. The Mine Safety and Health Administration, the Consumer Product Safety Commission, and the National Highway Traffic Safety Administration also lack any formal mechanisms for identifying potential conflicts of interest or for assessing the level of industry influence over the research.
In general, industry-funded studies are also subject to far less oversight than comparable federally funded studies. The data underlying private research do not have to be made public, unlike the data from federally sponsored research. A privately funded study can also avoid external scrutiny simply by being labeled “confidential business information.” One study by the Government Accountability Office found that a majority of the applications submitted to the EPA to market new chemicals contained science-based information that industry had labeled confidential.
As a result of these trends, Lisa Bero says, science has become one of the most powerful tools that private companies can use to fight regulation. The strategy they most often deploy was pioneered by the tobacco industry, which learned to foment scientific uncertainty as a means of staving off regulation. A famous tobacco industry document from 1969 spells out the strategy succinctly: “Doubt is our product, since it is the best means of competing with the ‘body of fact’ that exists in the mind of the general public. It is also the means of establishing controversy.”
In 2003, Frank Luntz, a political consultant to the Republican Party, recommended using the same strategy to combat public environmental concerns. “Voters believe that there is no consensus about global warming within the scientific community,” he wrote. “Should the public come to believe the scientific issues are settled, their views about global warming will change accordingly. Therefore, you need to make the lack of scientific certainty a primary issue in the debate.”
“Some policymakers fail to recognize that all studies are not created equal,” says Michaels, the author of a forthcoming book, Doubt Is Their Product: How Industry’s Assault on Science Threatens Your Health. “This results in the existence of what appear to be equal and opposite studies, encouraging policymakers to do nothing in the face of what appear to be contradictory findings.”
Virtually everyone interviewed for this article agrees about one thing: The U.S. government must strengthen its investment in science. The members of Norman Augustine’s 2005 National Academies panel continue to call for an immediate doubling of federal investment in basic science, arguing that basic science is a quintessential public good that only the federal government can properly fund. The rewards of basic research are risky and diffuse, making it difficult for individual companies to invest in.
The question of whether privatization has tipped the balance too far from noncommercial, public-interest science is more contested. “I’m more worried about the converse: Not that industry is dominating science but rather that government is abdicating what I think should be its role,” panel member Richard Zare says. Augustine agrees, but he acknowledges that commercialization of the public sphere does present challenges. “The environment we’ve seen does apply pressure in the direction of more applied work at our universities and our government labs. It just requires balance and that’s what makes it difficult,” he says. “If the end product of basic research is articles published in scientific journals, that’s very commendable, but it doesn’t likely impact on the economy short-term. On the other hand, if scientific research is neglected to focus on near-term, quick payoff pursuits, then very quickly the supply of knowledge will be exhausted.”
Some critics of privatization say that more public funding is pivotal not just for basic science but for public health and regulatory science as well. Their argument is much the same: Who else, other than the federal government, can ensure that this science for the public good is reliably carried out? They also say stronger “public interest” protections are urgently needed: stricter conflict of interest rules in both academia and the government, and prohibitions against commercial ghostwriting and corporate control of statistical analysis and raw data.
Once the genie is out of the bottle, it isn’t easy to get it back in. The more that public-sector scientists become invested in the status quo—through industry grants, patents, and the like—the less likely they are to support reforms. Not so long ago, academics and government scientists insured that the basic building blocks of science were freely available to everyone. Today, the Columbia economist Richard Nelson points out, a sizable portion of this public knowledge is private property. Is this something that should—or even could—be reversed?
The dilemma, says Eric Campbell of Harvard, is that industry partnerships yield many positive benefits: funding opportunities, the conversion of knowledge into products that benefit the public, rewards for inventors, jobs, economic growth. On the other hand, “the fundamental reason the public invests in science is out of the belief that it represents truth, untainted by commercial interests,” he says. “So to call that into question, I think, is really one of the great risks.”
_________________
LittleWing sometime in July 2007 wrote:
Unfortunately, it's so elementary, and the big time investors behind the drive in the stock market aren't so stupid. This isn't the false economy of 2000.
The threat is money—specifically, the decline of government support for science and the growing dominance of private spending over American research. - GV
Lawdy lawdy hallelujah! Govament knows best!!! Govament knows best!!! Where can I get some more kool-aid?!!!
Joined: Sat Oct 16, 2004 11:54 pm Posts: 12287 Location: Manguetown Gender: Male
So private companies cant conduct their own researchs because its not for the "people interests" ? Only the gov is wise to know what is good for the people?
In soviet russia the subject researches you!
_________________ There's just no mercy in your eyes There ain't no time to set things right And I'm afraid I've lost the fight I'm just a painful reminder Another day you leave behind
Joined: Sat Oct 16, 2004 10:51 pm Posts: 14534 Location: Mesa,AZ
That article is missing something. It mentions that government funding has declined since 1965, and that it's a Bad Thing. But what about before 1965? How much government funding was there before 1950, when we invented such things as... let's see... the automobile, the television, the radio, the light bulb, steam power, the airplane, well you get the point... Even computer technology has been mostly funded by large corporations with something to gain from it, such as IBM, Intel, etc.
Now government-sponsored research... Let's see.... Weapons of mass destruction, microwaves that map out the surface temperature of objects inside, etc... I'm sure government researchers have come up with plenty of useful inventions, but the lions share of that research money goes towards garbage that is not, nor will it ever be, of any practical use to society.
I especially like this part:
Quote:
Early this year, BP (formerly British Petroleum) announced it was signing the largest proposed academia-industry research alliance in U.S. history: a 10-year, $500 million agreement with UC Berkeley, Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory, and the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign to study biofuels and the production of genetically modified crops that might improve their energy efficiency. As of this writing, the deal is still being negotiated. However, according to Berkeley’s official proposal, released in early March, the deal is unusual in many respects. First, it is huge, spanning roughly 25 labs at three campuses. Second, it permits 50 BP employees to lease commercial research space on campus, side by side with Berkeley’s traditional academic labs. On the academic side, all research is publishable. On the BP side, by contrast, the research is proprietary; there is no obligation to publish.
Tadeusz Patzek, an engineering professor at Berkeley who formerly worked as a scientist at Shell, believes the deal compromises the university’s ability to look objectively at long-term energy solutions to global warming. He fears that professors, following the money, will steer their research toward BP’s specified area of commercial interest—biofuels—without adequately exploring other energy options. Patzek’s concerns are supported by survey research in the medical field conducted by David Blumenthal and Eric Campbell, policy analysts at Harvard University. Their research finds that academic scientists who receive industry funding are significantly more likely to select research projects that have a higher potential for commercial application. Industry ties, they report, are also associated with longer delays on publication, confidentiality restrictions, and a greater withholding of information from academic peers.
Here we have BP clearly funding research for improved energy efficiency, and some idiot has the guff to complain that some other area of research will miss out because of it, and that the research that they paid for won't be available for the entire world to mooch off of as easily. Here's an idea: if you have something really useful to research, it shouldn't be very difficult at all to get someone to pay for it. And if the researchers working for BP come up with something useful, I'm sure the other energy producers will buy the technology from BP.
_________________
John Adams wrote:
In my many years I have come to a conclusion that one useless man is a shame, two is a law firm, and three or more is a congress.
Joined: Sun Oct 17, 2004 4:01 am Posts: 19477 Location: Brooklyn NY
LittleWing wrote:
Quote:
The threat is money—specifically, the decline of government support for science and the growing dominance of private spending over American research. - GV
Lawdy lawdy hallelujah! Govament knows best!!! Govament knows best!!! Where can I get some more kool-aid?!!!
Only if it's run by the military!
_________________
LittleWing sometime in July 2007 wrote:
Unfortunately, it's so elementary, and the big time investors behind the drive in the stock market aren't so stupid. This isn't the false economy of 2000.
Joined: Fri Oct 22, 2004 12:20 am Posts: 5198 Location: Connecticut Gender: Male
thodoks wrote:
Buffalohed wrote:
thodoks wrote:
blah blah blah
Obviously you have never taken an economics class!
Sorry, it had to be done.
wait...what?
Yeah really, Buffalohed. His post was extremely interesting. (Or her post, sorry I didn't check). I'm suprised to see you write something like that, and yes I read all your posts here. thodoks had a couple great posts, and in my VERY humble opinion, only an economics pro could argue. But I know little on the subject, so maybe I'm wrong. Doubt it though.
If you were being sarcastic, then not only do I apologize but I also applaud you for not using the stupid arrow.
Should we worry that the people of China, India and other undeveloped countries are getting richer? Apparently so, according to the newspapers and the "experts" they quote. They don't come right out and say that global prosperity is bad for us. Instead they say, as The New York Times recently said, "As development rolls across once-destitute countries at a breakneck pace, lifting billions out of poverty, demand for food, metals and fuel is red-hot, and suppliers are struggling to meet it. Prices are spiraling, and Americans find themselves in what amounts to a bidding war with overseas buyers for products as diverse as milk and gasoline."
It is certainly true that China's economy is expanding dramatically -- 10 percent last year. The Chinese build factories like crazy to pump out the inexpensive exports we Americans love to buy. To do that, Chinese producers have to purchase oil, steel and lots of other commodities. The new demand drives prices up.
And as the Chinese and other people get richer, they improve their diets and eat more meat, putting pressure on world food prices.
So media handwringers suggest we should worry about the poor becoming rich.
Actually, we shouldn't. It would be a sad world if one person's economic success depended on another's failure.
More of us would understand this if we learned what the great economics writer Henry Hazlitt preached in his classic book, "Economics in One Lesson": "The art of economics consists in looking not merely at the immediate but at the longer effects of any act or policy."
In the short run, richer Chinese and Indians bid up the prices of things. But that's just the beginning of the story. Increased demand and higher prices create opportunities for entrepreneurs.
When the price of, say, oil goes up, entrepreneurs and inventors have a strong incentive to: 1) find more, 2) find alternatives, and 3) find ways to use oil more efficiently. You and I cannot foresee what they will invent, but that means nothing. Predictions about the end of progress have been issued countless times. There is no reason to think they will be right this time.
Assuming government stays out of the way. Our current "leaders" are full of promises about "protecting" workers and industries, creating new "green" industries, and starting worker-retraining programs. For example, Hillary Clinton promises government support for "research (to) stimulate the development of new technologies and life-saving medicines." Mitt Romney wants "to initiate a bold, far-reaching research initiative -- an Energy Revolution, if you will. It will be our generation's equivalent of the Manhattan Project or the mission to the moon."
The media lap it up, apparently believing that no one will produce unless our wise leaders create an inducement. Nonsense.
The market would deliver the goods if government doesn't impose crippling regulations and tax away everyone's capital to fund its coercive utopian schemes. I like what Henry David Thoreau once said: "This government never furthered any enterprise but by the alacrity with which it got out of the way."
George Mason University economist Alexander Tabarrok has another way to demonstrate the benefits of spreading prosperity. Tabarrok wrote in Forbes recently that the bigger the market, the more worthwhile it is for companies to make products that require costly research and development, such as medicines and chemicals. As the Chinese and Indians become more able to buy things, businesses everywhere will find it profitable to make products that yesterday weren't profitable enough. The result will be cures for diseases and other products that make our lives better.
Tabarrok takes this a step further: "Amazingly, there are only about 6 million scientists and engineers in the entire world, nearly a quarter of whom are in the U.S. Poverty means that millions of potentially world-class scientists today spend their lives trying to eke out a subsistence living, rather than leading mankind's charge into the future. But if the world as a whole were as wealthy as the U.S. and were devoting the same share of population to research and development, there would be more than five times as many scientists and engineers worldwide."
When it comes to being wealthy, the more the merrier.
_________________ There's just no mercy in your eyes There ain't no time to set things right And I'm afraid I've lost the fight I'm just a painful reminder Another day you leave behind
Should we worry that the people of China, India and other undeveloped countries are getting richer? Apparently so, according to the newspapers and the "experts" they quote. They don't come right out and say that global prosperity is bad for us. Instead they say, as The New York Times recently said, "As development rolls across once-destitute countries at a breakneck pace, lifting billions out of poverty, demand for food, metals and fuel is red-hot, and suppliers are struggling to meet it. Prices are spiraling, and Americans find themselves in what amounts to a bidding war with overseas buyers for products as diverse as milk and gasoline."
It is certainly true that China's economy is expanding dramatically -- 10 percent last year. The Chinese build factories like crazy to pump out the inexpensive exports we Americans love to buy. To do that, Chinese producers have to purchase oil, steel and lots of other commodities. The new demand drives prices up.
And as the Chinese and other people get richer, they improve their diets and eat more meat, putting pressure on world food prices.
So media handwringers suggest we should worry about the poor becoming rich.
Actually, we shouldn't. It would be a sad world if one person's economic success depended on another's failure.
More of us would understand this if we learned what the great economics writer Henry Hazlitt preached in his classic book, "Economics in One Lesson": "The art of economics consists in looking not merely at the immediate but at the longer effects of any act or policy."
In the short run, richer Chinese and Indians bid up the prices of things. But that's just the beginning of the story. Increased demand and higher prices create opportunities for entrepreneurs.
When the price of, say, oil goes up, entrepreneurs and inventors have a strong incentive to: 1) find more, 2) find alternatives, and 3) find ways to use oil more efficiently. You and I cannot foresee what they will invent, but that means nothing. Predictions about the end of progress have been issued countless times. There is no reason to think they will be right this time.
Assuming government stays out of the way. Our current "leaders" are full of promises about "protecting" workers and industries, creating new "green" industries, and starting worker-retraining programs. For example, Hillary Clinton promises government support for "research (to) stimulate the development of new technologies and life-saving medicines." Mitt Romney wants "to initiate a bold, far-reaching research initiative -- an Energy Revolution, if you will. It will be our generation's equivalent of the Manhattan Project or the mission to the moon."
The media lap it up, apparently believing that no one will produce unless our wise leaders create an inducement. Nonsense.
The market would deliver the goods if government doesn't impose crippling regulations and tax away everyone's capital to fund its coercive utopian schemes. I like what Henry David Thoreau once said: "This government never furthered any enterprise but by the alacrity with which it got out of the way."
George Mason University economist Alexander Tabarrok has another way to demonstrate the benefits of spreading prosperity. Tabarrok wrote in Forbes recently that the bigger the market, the more worthwhile it is for companies to make products that require costly research and development, such as medicines and chemicals. As the Chinese and Indians become more able to buy things, businesses everywhere will find it profitable to make products that yesterday weren't profitable enough. The result will be cures for diseases and other products that make our lives better.
Tabarrok takes this a step further: "Amazingly, there are only about 6 million scientists and engineers in the entire world, nearly a quarter of whom are in the U.S. Poverty means that millions of potentially world-class scientists today spend their lives trying to eke out a subsistence living, rather than leading mankind's charge into the future. But if the world as a whole were as wealthy as the U.S. and were devoting the same share of population to research and development, there would be more than five times as many scientists and engineers worldwide."
When it comes to being wealthy, the more the merrier.
in regards to "green" jobs. the market hasn't delivered. they are being delivered in germany or denmark or elsewhere in europe because of government policies promoting them and helping to ensure green energy is on a level playing field with conventional sources.
Users browsing this forum: No registered users and 14 guests
You cannot post new topics in this forum You cannot reply to topics in this forum You cannot edit your posts in this forum You cannot delete your posts in this forum You cannot post attachments in this forum